The Costs of Tariffs

The Costs of Tariffs

A drone view of trailers parked at Stellantis’s Chrysler Windsor Assembly facility in Windsor, Ontario, Canada, February 4, 2025.
A drone view of trailers parked at Stellantis’s Chrysler Windsor Assembly facility in Windsor, Ontario, Canada, February 4, 2025. Carlos Osorio/Reuters

CFR President and former U.S. Trade Representative Michael Froman analyzes the potential economic consequences and broader impacts on global trade norms of President Donald Trump’s imposition of tariffs on Canada, China, and Mexico.

February 7, 2025 2:14 pm (EST)

A drone view of trailers parked at Stellantis’s Chrysler Windsor Assembly facility in Windsor, Ontario, Canada, February 4, 2025.
A drone view of trailers parked at Stellantis’s Chrysler Windsor Assembly facility in Windsor, Ontario, Canada, February 4, 2025. Carlos Osorio/Reuters
Article
Current political and economic issues succinctly explained.

Michael Froman is president of the Council on Foreign Relations.

More From Our Experts

Over the weekend, President Donald Trump announced that the United States was going to impose 25 percent tariffs on goods from its two neighbors, Canada and Mexico, and 10 percent tariffs on all goods from China. Economists predicted chaos. Investors braced for impact. Trading partners scrambled to respond.

More on:

Trade

Tariffs

Canada

United States

Mexico

By the end of the workday on Monday, Canada and Mexico had managed to secure a thirty-day delay by pledging to ramp up their efforts to prevent the flow of migrants and drugs through their borders. But at midnight on Tuesday, the tariffs against China took effect, with Trump calling them merely an “opening salvo.” For now, the market’s reaction has been relatively muted. 

The tariffs should come as no surprise: Trump was acting on a deeply held belief and fulfilling a key campaign promise. But what’s less clear is what Trump was hoping to get out of this tariff play. The president seems to have multiple goals in mind. Whether he will succeed depends on which he prioritizes. 

One purpose seems to be to extract concessions in negotiations over a range of non-trade issues, from migration to drugs. The announcement of tariffs did immediately bring the Canadian and Mexican governments to the table, and the White House has made much of the changes they unveiled in response.

More From Our Experts

Canadian Prime Minister Justin Trudeau announced the appointment of a “fentanyl czar” and reiterated his prior commitment to spend hundreds of millions of dollars more on border security. Mexican President Claudia Sheinbaum promised to send ten thousand National Guard soldiers to the U.S. border, joining the more than ten thousand troops already there.

Trump also hopes that tariffs will bring production back home and eliminate bilateral trade deficits. In remarks delivered by video to Davos, he exhorted foreign companies to shift their production to the United States. “Come make your product in America, and we will give you among the lowest taxes of any nation on Earth,” he said. “But if you don’t make your product in America, which is your prerogative, then, very simply, you will have to pay a tariff.”

More on:

Trade

Tariffs

Canada

United States

Mexico

Onshoring production is a long-term project. It takes time to reorder supply chains and invest in new factories. Doing so would almost certainly raise the costs of production, making the goods less competitive and more expensive for consumers and end users. In some cases, onshoring is simply infeasible. Is the United States suddenly going to turn over vast amounts of land to grow all the tomatoes and avocados now imported from Mexico? If so, who is going to harvest them if Trump deports migrant workers?

Revenue seems to be another goal, with the president suggesting that tariffs might replace the federal income tax. As he explained in his inaugural address in January, “Instead of taxing our citizens to enrich other countries, we will tariff and tax foreign countries to enrich our citizens.” In his address to the Davos crowd, he claimed that tariffs would “direct hundreds of billions of dollars and even trillions of dollars into our Treasury.” Trump has proposed creating an “external revenue service” to collect the money.

Trump is almost certain to be disappointed on this front: 92 percent of the tariffs collected during his first term went to compensate American farmers for the cost of other countries’ retaliation, netting very little for the U.S. Treasury. Moreover, if tariffs work in reducing imports and promoting American production, there should be little revenue to collect.

The best evidence suggests that tariffs are paid largely by domestic consumers and manufacturers, not foreign producers. They effectively act as a tax on Americans, and a particularly regressive one at that, given that the lower a household’s income, the greater a proportion of its income it spends on imported household goods.

Trump has always resisted that characterization. So what was notable about a message he posted to his social media platform on Sunday was that—for the first time, so far as I can tell—he admitted that tariffs might impose costs on Americans. “WILL THERE BE SOME PAIN?” he asked on Truth Social. “YES, MAYBE (AND MAYBE NOT!)”

Indeed, there are three categories of costs that protectionist measures carry. The first is the cost of implementation. If tariffs are imposed on the more than $75 billion worth of agricultural products that the United States imports annually from Canada and Mexico, grocery stores, which operate on narrow profit margins, are going to pass that on to consumers. The price of Alberta beef and Michoacán avocados will go up.

The second is the cost of retaliation. Even as they attempted to negotiate a last-minute deal with Trump, Canada and Mexico had already prepared retaliatory measures. Canada published its list, which included goods from Republican-leaning states, such as Florida-grown oranges and Ohio-made appliances.

On Tuesday, China hit back with a barrage of measures of its own, announcing 15 percent and 10 percent tariffs on a range of goods, tighter export restrictions on key minerals, and an anti-monopoly investigation into Google. If Beijing’s tariffs take effect, as they are scheduled to do on February 10, then American companies will find it more difficult to export coal, oil, liquified natural gas, agricultural machinery, and pick-up trucks to China.

The final category of costs is perhaps the most corrosive: the cost of imitation, which arises when other countries follow the United States’ example in imposing their own tariffs and selectively adhering to the rules. When the architect of the rules-based economic order begins to pick and choose which rules to follow, other countries will have greater cause to follow suit. That, in turn, can cause direct problems for the United States down the road.

As CFR Senior Fellow Benn Steil has noted, since the first Trump administration used the national security exception to impose tariffs on Canadian and European steel and aluminum (an exception that had previously been invoked only rarely), other countries have increasingly cited national security as an excuse to tariff everything from alcoholic beverages to animal feed to door frames. Now, there are more than ninety barriers to trade based on the national security rationale.

Trump’s recent recognition that tariffs can cause pain is an important step in addressing the question of how much American consumers, workers, farmers, and ranchers are willing to pay for the chance to accomplish the tariffs’ goals. Prices will go up, growth will slow, and jobs could be lost. Conceivably, Americans are willing to pay something. If tariffs become the go-to tool, we will learn how much pain the public can stomach.

Of course, it’s also possible that few, if any, tariffs will ultimately be imposed. Trump seems quite comfortable pursuing an on-again, off-again approach to tariffs to gain the attention of foreign leaders and instill fear in the rest of the world—an economic version of the “madman” theory associated with President Richard Nixon. This might well work in the short run.

But if he keeps issuing threats, only to backtrack, the president might find that other countries are starting to take him less seriously as a leader and see the United States as less reliable as an ally. At a time when China is wooing other countries by positioning itself as the defender of globalization, multilateralism, and the rules-based system, America’s relative position as a global leader might well slip.

Creative Commons
Creative Commons: Some rights reserved.
Close
This work is licensed under Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0) License.
View License Detail
Close

Top Stories on CFR

Europe

On the eighty-first anniversary of D-Day, CFR President Michael Froman and senior fellows discuss the Trump administration’s diminished appetite for engagement in European security affairs—even as the Russia-Ukraine war drags on.

Ukraine

The Sanctioning Russia Act would impose history’s highest tariffs and tank the global economy. Congress needs a better approach, one that strengthens existing sanctions and adds new measures the current bill ignores.

China Strategy Initiative

At the Shangri-La dialogue in Singapore last week, U.S. Secretary of Defense Pete Hegseth said that the United States would be expanding its defense partnership with India. His statement was in line with U.S. policy over the last two decades, which, irrespective of the party in power, has sought to cultivate India as a serious defense partner. The U.S.-India defense partnership has come a long way. Beginning in 2001, the United States and India moved from little defense cooperation or coordination to significant gestures that would lay the foundation of the robust defense partnership that exists today—such as India offering access to its facilities after 9/11 to help the United States launch operations in Afghanistan or the 123 Agreement in 2005 that paved the way for civil nuclear cooperation between the two countries. In the United States, there is bipartisan agreement that a strong defense partnership with India is vital for its Indo-Pacific strategy and containing China. In India, too, there is broad political support for its strategic partnership with the United States given its immense wariness about its fractious border relationship with China. Consequently, the U.S.-India bilateral relationship has heavily emphasized security, with even trade tilting toward defense goods. Despite the massive changes to the relationship in the last few years, and both countries’ desire to develop ever-closer defense ties, differences between the United States and India remain. A significant part of this has to do with the differing norms that underpin the defense interests of each country. The following Council on Foreign Relations (CFR) memos by defense experts in three countries are part of a larger CFR project assessing India’s approach to the international order in different areas, and illustrate India’s positions on important defense issues—military operationalization, cooperation in space, and export controls—and how they differ with respect to the United States and its allies. Sameer Lalwani (Washington, DC) argues that the two countries differ in their thinking about deterrence, and that this is evident in three categories crucial to defense: capability, geography, and interoperability. When it comes to increasing material capabilities, for example, India prioritizes domestic economic development, including developing indigenous capabilities (i.e., its domestic defense-industrial sector). With regard to geography, for example, the United States and its Western allies think of crises, such as Ukraine, in terms of global domino effects; India, in contrast, thinks regionally, and confines itself to the effects on its neighborhood and borders (and, as the recent crisis with Pakistan shows, India continues to face threats on its border, widening the geographic divergence with the United States). And India’s commitment to strategic autonomy means the two countries remain far apart on the kind of interoperability required by modern military operations. Yet there is also reason for optimism about the relationship as those differences are largely surmountable. Dimitrios Stroikos (London) argues that India’s space policy has shifted from prioritizing socioeconomic development to pursuing both national security and prestige. While it is party to all five UN space treaties that govern outer space and converges with the United States on many issues in the civil, commercial, and military domains of space, India is careful with regard to some norms. It favors, for example, bilateral initiatives over multilateral, and the inclusion of Global South countries in institutions that it believes to be dominated by the West. Konark Bhandari (New Delhi) argues that India’s stance on export controls is evolving. It has signed three of the four major international export control regimes, but it has to consistently contend with the cost of complying, particularly as the United States is increasingly and unilaterally imposing export control measures both inside and outside of those regimes. When it comes to export controls, India prefers trade agreements with select nations, prizes its strategic autonomy (which includes relations with Russia and China through institutions such as the Shanghai Cooperation Organization and the BRICS), and prioritizes its domestic development. Furthermore, given President Donald Trump’s focus on bilateral trade, the two countries’ differences will need to be worked out if future tech cooperation is to be realized.